Skip to contentSkip to navigation

Five Overlooked Principles Shaping the Destiny of Your Business

Until you grasp Turing’s theory of computability, Coase theorem of transaction costs, Bell’s law of computer classes, Baldwin and Clarke’s concept of modularity, and Nakamoto’s law of the distributed ledger, you’re not prepared to lead a digital company.

The most important changes are often the least obvious. That’s especially true in business, where changes are taking place on a greater scale than ever before. The advent of digital technology has brought a number of these dynamics to the forefront. They can be thought of as principles. Like Moore’s law or Murphy’s law, they explain the way the world works.

If you’re in business in the 2010s, an understanding of these five principles is crucial, because digital disruption is quickly becoming the new normal. Many growth strategies that may have worked well in the past no longer pack a punch. The principles help explain not just what will happen to your company next, but why.

Turing’s theory of computability: Machines can calculate any of the ever-growing number of problems that are possible to calculate. In the 1930s and 1940s, the English mathematician Alan Turing (whose life was dramatized in the 2014 thriller The Imitation Game), made some pathbreaking observations about computability and its ramifications. He identified what he called “computable” activities: any task that a theoretical machine (in this case, a mathematical model with a process similar to a computer) can address. Having determined that computability can be identified mathematically, Turing then postulated that machines have the capacity to perform computable tasks as well as human beings can. In his e-book Introduction to Computing: Explorations in Language, Logic, and Machines, University of Virginia professor David Evans devotes a chapter to computability. “A problem is computable if it can be solved by some algorithm,” he explains. “A problem that is noncomputable cannot be solved by any algorithm.”

In 1950, Alan Turing provided a demonstration of computability that is still remembered today as the “Turing test.” He set up an experiment in which he asked his subjects to exchange typed messages with an entity in another room. Many onlookers could not guess correctly whether there was a person or a computer generating the responses. This demonstrated that a computer program could make a convincing representation of human intelligence, good enough to function as well as a person on that task. Or, as Turing put it in a paper (pdf) at the time, the program could “play the imitation game satisfactorily” for any computable task. He predicted that in 50 years machines would, for five minutes, be able to fool a human questioner 30 percent of the time. His prediction came true in 2014.

At the time Turing published his original paper, only a small number of activities were computable. But he foresaw that as digital computing continued to evolve, the number of computable activities would grow — and, indeed, they continue to grow in number and influence today. Thus, for an ever-growing body of human endeavor, machines are as competent as people, or even more so. Moreover, no one can say for sure which activities will be susceptible to Turing’s theory next, nor which will be immune.

It would be hard to exaggerate the significance of Turing’s work on computability and artificial intelligence. It launched the computer age, establishing the fact that everything digital, from the first computer to the cell phones that are ubiquitous today, has the potential to overtake work currently done by people. When highly valued digital technologies emerge, such as search engines, ride-hailing apps, automated teller machines, travel-booking websites, and many others, they inevitably displace human effort — and in the process, they fundamentally change their industries.

The impact of increasing computability explains why established companies are so strongly affected by digitization. In a world where anything businesses do might soon be done by a computer, they have to continually redefine themselves along digital lines — whether it’s Walmart acquiring Internet retailer Jet, GE making its industrial products “smart,” or John Deere developing robotic lawn mowers. Among the tasks expected to become computable before long are basic due diligence in M&A transactions, real-time language-to-language translation (such as English to Chinese), some forms of programming, and most of the world’s motor vehicle driving.

At the same time, worries (or hopes) that computers will replace human beings entirely are probably premature. Though many aspects of human activity can be carved out by the wave of increasing computability, much of what people do is beyond the capacity of machines to replicate. Turing himself argued that some tasks would never be computable. Driving and performing due diligence may be the province of machines before long, but only humans can decide where to travel and what companies to buy.

Coase theorem of transaction costs: Aside from transaction costs, the most efficient outcome will prevail in any market. The critical phrase in this theorem is aside from transaction costs. The theorem means that the investment of money, time, and attention devoted to the exchange of goods and services will determine how well your company competes. Or, put another way, the only companies with growth potential are those that keep their internal transaction costs (their own expenses) lower than their external transaction costs (the expense of doing business with others).

Starting in the late 1930s, economist Ronald Coase considered at length the question of why firms come into being and why they decline. (He received the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1991, in part for this work.) His ultimate conclusion has become known as the Coase theorem: a company becomes viable when it’s able to perform its activities in-house more cheaply than it could by outsourcing them to the market. If that weren’t the case, there wouldn’t be companies at all; commerce would operate solely through the markets, with people continually forming and reforming themselves into project-based enterprises.

Companies exist, in short, because when you try to do business alone, without being part of a larger enterprise, you incur many different kinds of external transaction costs. The expenses associated with gathering and sharing information, maintaining infrastructure, bargaining with others, managing activity, and enforcing compliance are all reduced when you don’t have to negotiate a new transaction every time you start something new. Larger firms have an advantage because they can handle more of these activities internally than smaller firms can.

But companies also have internal costs that the market doesn’t carry. Operating at a large scale requires layers of management and internal oversight performed by employees who would not be needed in a smaller firm. There are also costs involved with internal politics; for example, when a project fails because others disapprove of it, the funding spent to develop it is forfeited. This pattern disproportionately affects large companies, where there tend to be more internal bureaucratic constraints. Moreover, internal costs associated with staff (such as healthcare and training) can soar in a large company, but would be externalized if everyone were a contractor.

The Coase theorem explains the curbs on growth that confound many companies, large and small. A company can grow only as long as its internal costs, including all overhead, are lower than its external costs. Once internal costs equal or surpass external costs and the company has reached the point of diminishing returns, it will stop expanding. Because internal transaction costs are often difficult to spot, the leaders of the company may not realize why it’s struggling.

New digital technologies have raised the pressures associated with the Coase theorem because they reduce external costs. Some observers believe that these technologies will sound the death knell for large companies. Search engines, for instance, have made it much easier and cheaper to obtain information today than it was in the past, and thus have eroded an advantage formerly held by large companies with great resources.

But digitization also reduces internal costs — at least for companies that leverage the technology effectively. This has changed the economics of internal organization. Take, for example, cloud-based services, which coordinate capacity and functionality more easily and rapidly, allowing for higher levels of productivity with the same staff and for temporary expansion when needed without large capital expenditures. The Web services units of Amazon, Microsoft, and Google have capitalized on this trend, and such services will likely proliferate. Some companies are already building technological platforms linking all parts of their enterprise and value chain for relatively low cost compared with the IT projects of yesteryear. They are thus becoming much more competitive than they were before.

 
Get the strategy+business newsletter delivered to your inbox

(sample)

 

As digitization continues, transaction costs will continue to decline. This will affect decisions about which activities to keep inside an organization and which to acquire from the outside. Some things that used to be cheaper on the inside will now become more expensive — for example, the maintenance of R&D staffs. Hence the value of open innovation. Meanwhile, things that used to benefit from outsourcing, such as HR and training, may now become less expensive internally, because the de-layering of hierarchies may allow more informal (and therefore less expensive) talent management and recruiting. The only thing that won’t change is the basic equation: The lower your internal costs compared with your external costs, the more likely your company is to grow.

Bell’s law on the birth and death of computer classes: Roughly every decade, a new class of lower-priced computing devices emerges — and changes everything. Gordon Bell is among the most celebrated engineers in the computer industry. He designed most of the influential PDP series of minicomputers at Digital Equipment Corporation; he conceived and cofounded the first museum of computer history, in Boston; and more recently, his experiments with “life-logging” — automatically putting the images, sounds, and documents of everyday experience into digital archival storage — have deepened our understanding of what computers can do.

Bell is also a great thinker. In his seminal 1972 article (pdf), he observed that every decade or so, advances in semiconductors, storage, interfaces, and networks lead to the development of a new, lower-priced computer “class,” and a new industry and marketplace along with it. This tends to (at least partially) supplant the old class; smartphones displaced many personal computers, which displaced minicomputers, which displaced mainframes. Of course, mainframes still survive as supercomputers and cloud servers, but the new classes of computers continue to redefine possibilities. Bell’s law suggests that technology evolves through punctuated equilibrium, repeatedly thrusting the world into a new normal.

When highly valued digital technologies emerge, they inevitably displace human effort — and fundamentally change their industries.

Every time a shift in computer classes takes place, the impact goes far beyond technology. New platforms, new forms of programming, and new types of network interfaces appear. In business, a distinct new industry emerges, often with completely different companies in the lead. The old companies either adapt (as Apple did with the smartphone and Microsoft did with the cloud) or decline (like Digital Equipment Corporation, Gateway, Kaypro, Osborne, and many others).

The newest class is exemplified by the Internet of Things (IoT). It involves miniature computers, small enough to embed throughout industrial society and powerful enough to track, analyze, and communicate. This class, which has just appeared, is already fueling enormous growth. Banking, automobiles, defense, healthcare, and security are a few of the industries using the newest devices to innovate products and services. The opportunities that embedded computing can offer will become clearer as the IoT evolves, but there’s no doubt that this new class will be as transformative as its predecessors.

Baldwin and Clark’s concept of modularity: Breaking a technology or process into functionally relevant components facilitates innovation. In the late 1990s, Harvard Business School professors Carliss Baldwin and Kim Clark noted that modularity, also known as modular design, is a key driver of innovation speed. Modularity is a technique used in software development, automobile design, and other aspects of engineering. It breaks a complex technological project into a number of functionally relevant components — standardized where standardization is called for, and individually designed where differentiation is needed.

In a system with high modularity, the standardized parts, or modules, can easily be swapped out, upgraded, and adapted in different ways for different systems. Modularity makes it easier (and less expensive) to manage the complexity of a design. For example, some parts of a modular computer system can be opened up to outside innovators (who might design apps and other accessories for it) while other parts are kept proprietary and free of outside interference. A truly modular system can be tailored to individual customers without the entire design needing to be reinvented.

Baldwin and Clark’s study of industrial design found that the more modular a product is, the faster it can be innovated. Computers, for example, all have several standardized processors, mainboards, and hard drives. They also have USB ports that make it easy to upgrade peripherals such as headphones, storage, and flash drives without having to upgrade the computer itself. These interoperable components have not slowed down innovation; on the contrary, because computer makers still compete intensively, component development has helped focus R&D on features where differentiation matters.

The concept of modularity applies to companies as well. Relatively modular organizations can innovate more quickly than others, because the pace of their research and development is not slowed down by the slowest unit or product. Consider Amazon, which has developed an architecture of services that allows it to offer a complex array of offerings at lower cost points than its competitors. This is a key reason the Internet retailer has proved so adept at entering new industries and developing new offerings — including its own modular infrastructure, the Amazon Cloud.

Modularity in an organization does not require setting up separate R&D labs in complete isolation from each other. It does, however, require paying attention to the design of the R&D process, sharing some common processes and practices (such as, perhaps, procurement of materials and the use of cloud-based software platforms) while keeping other practices fully individual (such as the unique hardware and software features that competitors should not reverse engineer). Today, as companies make the move from analog to digital, modularity is crucial because speed and agility are crucial.

Nakamoto’s law of the distributed ledger: Transactions improve when trust is managed by the system, not by mediators. No one has yet called it “Nakamoto’s law,” but the principle underlying blockchain technology is already fundamental to the verification and certification practices of the future. In a technical paper (pdf) published in 2008, Satoshi Nakamoto (a pseudonym for an individual whose real identity remains undisclosed) observed that the Internet commerce of that time relied on financial institutions as a trusted third party to process electronic payments. This was unnecessarily complex and was vulnerable to deceit or failure. He posited that if two parties could electronically transact with one another without the need for an external overseer, online transactions would be easier and cheaper.

A few months later, Nakamoto released the first version of bitcoin: a digital currency with a distributed ledger, a peer-to-peer data technology that ensures verification through a software process called blockchain. Blockchain uses a digital distributed ledger to record transactions electronically, linking each new entry by code to the entry that came before. Verification takes place through network coordination. Computers all through the network contribute to bitcoin’s computation, storing the ledger and exchanging the codes that create new bitcoins. This distributed approach ensures that all the posted transactions are legitimate. No single member or group can compromise the integrity of a ledger distributed among so many participants.

Bitcoin and the distributed ledger have the potential to completely change the economics of trading, banking, voting, oversight, and other validated transactions. The number and size of transactions that can be cleared automatically, without institutional approval, are likely to rise dramatically. These transactions will be the basis for “smart contracts”: automated, legally binding, and self-enforcing transactional agreements. As trust-related risks (including reputational risks) become a thing of the past, companies will become more dynamic. They will be free to take new kinds of risk. Imagine buying real estate as easily as buying groceries, knowing that the transaction is safe because computers around the world, all linked together, provide the bona fides of all parties involved.

Nakamoto’s law is a natural extension of the other four principles described here. As Turing would have predicted, it digitizes verification, which had always been assumed to be a human domain. It represents a Coase-like reduction in transaction costs, which may reduce many of the costs associated with financial services. It is possible because of the rise of a new computer class, the interlinked servers and devices of today’s cloud-based software (and encryption). And it demonstrates the effectiveness of modularity. Although the core of the technology remains hidden, the bitcoins themselves fit together as interoperable blocks, each one derived from the code of the previous one.

The Power of the Five Principles

Taken together, these five principles have enormous economic ramifications. Although it’s impossible to predict the full extent of their impact, it’s clear they will change the structure and source of profit in a variety of industries around the world. Already, the shifts in computability, computer classes, transaction-cost dynamics, and modularity have enabled companies such as Amazon and Google to reach untold numbers of vendors and customers without racking up crushing operating expenses.

These principles also help us better understand the ways in which winning companies compete in today’s rapidly digitizing market. At the end of the day, great strategy depends on understanding the fundamentals of innovation, economics, and marketing, which are changing in terms of value creation. Power will flow to enterprises that embrace automation, reduce internal costs, make better use of advanced devices, design modularity into their products and services, and participate in blockchain-style verification systems. To be sure, the optimal approach will vary from one industry to another: A human third party may be enough to guarantee the security of transactions in some markets, whereas other markets will require virtual third-party validation through a blockchain system.

As industries continue to embrace full digitization, we will see a shift in the way experts talk about competition and growth. As with Moore’s law, the basic trends are readily apparent. But the way they play out, and the details of industry evolution that follow, will be full of surprises.

Author profile:

  • John Sviokla is a principal and U.S. marketing leader at PwC, where he also works with clients on strategy and innovation. He is the head of the Global Thought Leadership Institute and leads the Exchange, the firm’s think tank.
Get s+b's award-winning newsletter delivered to your inbox. Sign up No, thanks
Illustration of flying birds delivering information
Get the newsletter

Sign up now to get our top insights on business strategy and management trends, delivered straight to your inbox twice a week.